Cultural Property and Currency: Difference between pages

From Max-EuP 2012
(Difference between pages)
m 1 revision imported
 
m 1 revision imported
 
Line 1: Line 1:
__FORCETOC__  
__FORCETOC__  
by ''[[Kurt Siehr]]''
by ''[[Caroline Kleiner]]''


== 1. Notion ==
== 1. Concept, objective and goal ==


The notion ''cultural property or object'' (having its equivalents in other languages: ''Kulturgut'', ''kulturgode'','' kulturföremål'','' bien culturel'', ''πολιτιστικόν αγαθόν'','' bene ''or'' patrimonio culturale'','' cultuurgoed'','' dobro kultury'','' bem ''or'' património cultural'', культурное постояние, ''kulturminne ''or'' kulturföremål'','' biene'' or ''patrimonio cultural'','' kültür varlιk'','' kulturális tárgy'') has been known since modern times. In no European codification of private law, however, was this term used. Only later the term was introduced in special statutes aimed at protecting national cultural objects from export to foreign counties. Even in Italy, where the modern protection of cultural property originated with the ''Editto Doria Pamphilj'' (1802) and the ''Editto Pacca'' (1820), the term used was ''opere dell’Antichità ''(1802) or ''cose d’antichità e d’arte'' (statute of 1913) or ''cose di interesse storico e artistico'' (statute of 1939).  
Although currency is used in many different areas of law, no legal definition of this concept exists. Currency is a specific legal object that should not be confused with bank notes. Legal scholars often mention the relativity of this concept. It is indeed an abstract concept.


The first German Statute of 1919 prohibited the export of ‘art works’ in order to prevent the national ‘possession of art’ from being lost to foreign countries. It lasted until 1954, when in public international law the term ‘cultural property’ was used. Since that time, the term has also become common in other areas. The first official document that used this term was the Hague Convention of 14 May 1954 for the Protection of Cultural Property in the Event of Armed Conflict. The UNESCO Convention of 14 November 1970 on the Means of Prohibiting and Preventing the Illicit Import, Export and Transfer of Ownership of Cultural Property adopted the term ‘cultural property’ or ‘cultural object’ as did the [[UNIDROIT]] Convention of 14 June 1995 on Stolen and Illegally Exported Cultural Objects. The [[European Union]] also uses the term ‘cultural good’ or ‘cultural object’ (''bien culturel'') in Regulation 3911/92 on the Export of Cultural Goods and Directive 93/7 on the Return of Cultural Objects Unlawfully Removed from the Territory of a Member State. In more recent treaties, the term ‘cultural heritage’ (''patrimoine culturel'', ''Kulturerbe'', ''patrimonio culturale'', ''patrimonio cultural'') is preferred. This began with the UNESCO Convention of 21 November 1972 for the Protection of World Cultural and Natural Heritage. In this Convention, mainly immovable objects are protected and for these objects the term ‘cultural heritage’ is more appropriate than the terms ‘cultural property’ or ''bien culturel''. The term ‘cultural heritage’ was accepted later by the UNESCO Convention of 2 November 2001 on Underwater Cultural Heritage and by the UNESCO Convention of 17 October 2003 for the Safeguarding of the Intangible Cultural Heritage. In some languages, the term ‘heritage’ resolved the incorrect impression that, with ‘property’, only tangible objects are protected.
Currency, as a legal concept, should be distinguished from the notion of money. From an economic point of view, money is a medium of exchange, a unit of account and a measure of value. Conversely, currency is a legal concept: a specific monetary unit of a monetary system within a state or monetary zone. Currency is the backbone of a monetary system, which is itself the foundation of an economic order. Although both words exist in German (''Geld'' and ''Währung'') as well as in French (''argent'' and ''monnaie''), the distinction in English law is not exactly the same as the difference between ''Währung'' and ''Geld'' in German (for instance, the statute introducing the new Deutsche Mark in 1948 bore the title ''Währungsgesetz'' and not ''Geldgesetz''). The concept of ‘money’ (''Geld'') is therefore broader than the concept of ‘currency’ (''Währung''), which refers to the specific money of a state, and yet is the basis of its definition.


What cultural property is and what is meant with ‘cultural heritage’ is told to us by national statutes and international treaties. Therefore there is no need to try to define a universal notion of cultural property. Such an endeavour, in any event, would be in vain.  
A precise definition of the legal concept of currency is nonetheless hard to find. Currency is a wide-ranging concept that relates to many different legal areas, hence the elaboration of a general definition is challenging. The easiest approach consists in analysing the roles assumed by the concept of currency. In the context of legal relationships, currency has both an abstract and an actual function. The currency of account (''Rechnungswährung'', ''monnaie de compte'') determines the value of the monetary obligation. It fulfils the abstract function of money. The currency of account also corresponds to the ‘institutional notion of money’. The currency of payment (''die'' ''Zahlungswährung'', ''monnaie de paiement'') performs and discharges monetary obligations. It represents the actual function of money. Both functions, assuming respectively the role of a unit of account and a means of exchange, are intrinsically linked, yet they should be clearly distinguished from each other.


== 2. Importance in national substantive law ==
For a currency to fulfil both functions, it should contain different elements. The concept of currency can be restricted to three monetary components. All are necessary for the existence of a currency. First, the monetary unit, expressing a unit of value, plays the main role. A monetary unit is a unit of measure whose value is based on a convention. In the past, the value of a monetary unit used to be determined by a specific weight of noble metal. Today, its value is determined in accordance with the market demand. The second essential element composing a currency is located in its abstract purchasing power. Friedrich Carl von Savigny identified the notion of abstract purchasing power. It means that the currency implies a specific and subjective right that performs all types of obligations, even future ones. Thirdly, the unit of account reflecting a purchasing power needs an embodiment or a ‘bearer’ in order to materialize. These two last components are the core elements which enable a currency to serve as a medium of exchange. Moreover, the purchasing power can be embodied in different ‘bearers’. These embodiments or ‘bearers’ are the external aspect of the currency.


In national law, cultural property is important in five respects: for the law of ancient monuments, for protecting national treasures from export, for the return of foreign cultural objects illegally removed, for the return of Nazi-confiscated art objects to the former owners, and for the return guarantee (immunity) of loaned art from abroad.  
It is common to distinguish (at least in continental Europe) between coins, banknotes, bank money (also called credit money, ''Buchgeld'') and electronic money. But from a legal point of view, these bearers of purchasing power should be differentiated into only two categories. Coins and notes are monetary signs. Monetary signs are ‘commodities, which are divided into units of account, which serve as a medium of exchange to their nominal value according to the law, and which as such are recognized by the laws and cannot be refused by any creditor’ (Karsten Schmidt). Since the abrogation of the duty of the Central Bank to exchange notes against gold, bank notes can no longer be compared with bills of exchange. Coins and bank notes are therefore governed by the same legal regime as the one applied to commodities, but with some exceptions, such as their capacity to serve as a legal means of payment and the provisions against counterfeiting. Conversely, bank or credit money, as well as electronic money, are not commodities, but are credits towards private institutions. They are mostly bank deposits. The appellation bank money or credit money comes from the fact that the circulation of money is operated only under book transfers, without any manual exchange of any monetary commodities. In that perspective, no distinction should be made between bank money and e-money. The only difference is that nowadays all transfers are made electronically. Regardless of this fact, coins and banknotes (token money) and bank money merely represent different external forms of purchasing power which are divided into units of account and form, all together, money. These three monetary elements are closely linked with one another, but they are still regulated by different norms. This tripartite composition of a currency explains why, irrespective of its function in monetary obligations, different types of legal norms find application.  


a) The law of ancient monuments (''protection des monuments'', ''Denkmalschutz'', ''tutela dei monumenti'') is primarily special administrative (public) law, with certain repercussions in private law. It limits the exercise of otherwise free property rights in respect of objects subject to protection as ancient monuments. In statutes on ancient monuments, certain rules may be found with respect to treasure, according to which finds of scientific interest may be declared as state property.  
In private law and in [[Private International Law (PIL)|private international law (PIL)]], money raises a large number of questions. The answers to such questions depend on the functions money fulfils. In the context of monetary obligations, the first question to be answered is the determination of the money of account. According to the majority of scholars, the determination of which money is due is governed by the law of the obligation. This is the Swiss (Art&nbsp;147 §&nbsp;2 of the Swiss Private International Law Act (SPILA)) as well as the German view. In French law, the case law shows an inclination to analyse the question as an issue relating to the interpretation of contract. Secondly, one should consider the question of the value of the unit of account. Where the parties have foreseen a monetary clause, this clause is governed by the law applicable to the contract in which it is enshrined (''lex contractus''). German law and English law follow this approach. French case law has drawn another method and invented a new substantive rule, upon which monetary clauses in international contracts are always valid (Cour de Cassation, Cass. civ. 1<sup>re</sup>, 21&nbsp;June 1950, ''Messageries maritimes'', Rev. crit 1950, 609). If the parties have not foreseen such a clause, then the question arises as to which legal order decides upon the value of the currency of account, that is to say, whether the nominalism principle should apply. The application of the so-called ''lex monetae'' (''Währungsstatut'') was widespread up until the end of World War II. Today, the prominent position is to apply the law of the contract. One of the questions raised in relation to the currency of payment is precisely the determination of the currency of payment. More particularly, the question is whether an obligation providing for a foreign currency of payment can be discharged in local money. If German law is applicable, §&nbsp;244 [[Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch (BGB)|''Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch'' (BGB)]] provides that if a money debt stated in a currency other than the euro is payable within the country, then payment may be made in euros unless payment in the other currency has been expressly agreed to. In the context of conflict of laws, in Swiss law the determination of the currency of payment is governed by the law of payment, that is to say, the law of the place of payment or the ''lex loci solutionis'' (Art&nbsp;147 §&nbsp;3 SPILA). This is also the solution enshrined in Art&nbsp;10(2) of the Rome Convention and Art&nbsp;12(2) of Rome&nbsp;I Regulation (Reg&nbsp;593/2008), insofar as the currency of payment is seen as a manner of performance. This solution is linked to the fact that the [[Overriding Mandatory Provisions|overriding mandatory provisions]] (''lois de police'') of the state where the payment takes place are often applied.


b)&nbsp;Many countries protect their national treasures from being exported to foreign countries without government approval. If they pursue this policy (and do not, as the United States, reject such an approach), there are two possibilities. Either export may be delayed until a certain time or it may be completely prohibited. The first model is the English one. If a valuable national treasure is sold and is to be exported, but meets the Waverley criteria (close connection with British history and national life, or outstanding aesthetic importance, or outstanding significance for the study of some particular branch of art, learning or history), the export licence may be postponed for a certain time. If nobody is willing to buy the object for permanent stay in the country, the export licence has to be given.
== 2. Evolving tendencies of the law  ==


Most other countries have chosen the system of absolute export ban but with some differences. In Germany and Switzerland, there are special lists of cultural objects that must not leave the country without government licence (German Statute on the Protection of Cultural Objects against Removal, version of 8&nbsp;July 1999; Swiss Cultural Property Transfer Act of 20&nbsp;June 2003, Arts&nbsp;3 and 4). In certain other countries, no cultural objects are allowed to leave the country without government licence as, for example, Italy (Italian ''Codice dei beni culturali e del paesaggio'' of 22&nbsp;January 2004, Arts&nbsp;10&nbsp;ff) because they are of ''interesse artistico'','' storico'','' archeologico o etnoantropologico''. In addition to this protection, most cultural objects are unmerchantable (''res extra commercium'', ''demanio pubblico'', ''domaine public'') and cannot be sold and are not subject to prescription or statutes of limitation. Foreign courts, however, have in the past been unwilling to give effect to another country’s designation of an object as unmerchantable.
The theories aimed at explaining the origin of money were uncontested for a long time. According to the state theory of money developed by the economist Georg Friedrich Knapp, ‘[m]oney is a creature of law’. This theory constrains the concept because according to it, only monetary commodities issued by a state could be seen as money, thus excluding bank money. However, what can be concluded from this theory is that the state monopoly over money and its monopoly over the issuance of coins and notes are a component part of state sovereignty. It is beyond doubt that the state—or a supranational organization whose sovereignty has been granted by states—alone has the privilege to confer to commodities the status of legal tender and to authorize their circulation. As a consequence, only the state which issued a currency can define and regulate it. This principle was first set forth in 1929 by the Permanent Court of International Justice (PCIJ 12&nbsp;July 1929, ''Serbian Loans and Brazilian Loans'').


c)&nbsp;Within the European Union, all Member States are obliged to return illegally removed cultural objects to another Member State if the country of origin asks for return and is ready to pay compensation to the ''bona fide'' purchaser. This is provided by national legislation implementing Dir&nbsp;93/7and in the United Kingdom by the Return of Cultural Objects Regulation of 1994 (SI 1994/501).  
In contrast to the state theory of money, Arthur Nussbaum developed the sociological theory of money. According to Nussbaum, money is whatever is considered as such in the economic community or in the market. His theory explains particularly the phenomenon of emergency currency. The power of the state to create and circulate money is a privilege of the state, but is not a requirement for a currency to exist. However, the controversy on whether money is a creature of the law or a result of social activities is no longer relevant. As a legal institution, currency is based on its recognition by the state and is, in this sense, the product of legal orders. But it is absolutely not contradictory that money is the product of economic activities and in the meantime a product of the rule of law.  


d)&nbsp;In addition to these obligations under European law, many countries have committed themselves to return certain cultural objects according to well-recognized principles. Germany and other countries agreed to return objects according to the Washington Conference Principles of 3&nbsp;December 1998 on Nazi-confiscated Art.  
The debate has now shifted from the origin of money to its future. Two tendencies in the evolution of the private law of currency can be assessed. The first one concerns the ‘bearer’ or the manifestation of money (how the purchasing power is incorporated): it is related to the dematerialization of the circulation of money. The second tendency focuses on the monetary unit.


e)&nbsp;To protect art objects on loan from abroad from being seized by third persons, many countries have provided a return guarantee or immunity from seizure in favour of the institution giving the loan. Sometimes loans are only given if the borrowing institution guaranties the safe return of the art objects on loan. In the United Kingdom, the relevant provisions may be found in the Tribunals, Courts and Enforcement Act 2007 (Part 6, §§&nbsp;134–138), providing such immunity for cultural objects on loan. The same is true for Austria (Immunity Statute No&nbsp;133/2002), Germany (§&nbsp;20 German Statute for Preventing Art&nbsp;Objects from Export), Switzerland (Arts&nbsp;10&nbsp;ff Cultural Property Transfer Act) and other countries.  
The abstract nature of money was brought to light because of the dematerialization of its external forms. In the past, many authors argued that only token money (coins and notes), which were dealt with as chattels, corresponded to the notion of money. An amount of units registered on a bank account was a credit and not money. But with the exponential increase of cashless payments, the definition of money has obviously changed. Bank deposits are henceforth seen as money because they assume the function of money. E-money merely represents a step forward to the dematerialization of money. Only the manner of book entries has evolved; the so-called e-money remains money, since it is still evaluated through accounting units and embodies an abstract purchasing power.  


== 3. Importance in private international law (PIL) ==
In the meantime, the unification of currencies, for which the euro currency is the most representative example, is worth noticing. But this is not the unique example. In Africa, the ''Franc CFA'' is still shared by some former French colonies. A regional monetary union can also be achieved by means other than international conventions. The so-called dollarization that has emerged in Latin America, as well as the unilateral introduction of the euro in some European countries not part of the euro zone (Monaco, Andorra), illustrate this tendency. The states of the ''Mercosur'' are currently dealing with the issue of whether they should introduce a common currency or not. This tendency raises different questions: how the competence relating to money should be exercised and how to react to the unilateral adoption of the money by third states. As far as the euro is concerned, the Member States of the European Monetary Union have transferred their sovereign power. The German Federal Constitutional Court asserted that the transfer of competence was compatible with the German Constitution (''Grundgesetz'') in the ''Maastricht'' Judgment of 12&nbsp;October 1993 (BVerfGE 89, 155). The [[European Central Bank]] (ECB) only has competence over monetary policy and the competence to decide on monetary issues. The European legislature also provided for the principle of continuity of legal instruments in order to ensure the recognition of the euro by third states (Art&nbsp;3 Reg&nbsp;1103/97).


To date, there is no special rule of PIL for cultural objects. Movable cultural objects are still treated according to international [[Property Law (International)|property law]] and hence subject to the old rule of ''lex rei sitae''. Whether a cultural object may be acquired at all or be acquired ''bona fide'' or by prescription is decided according to the law governing the purported acquisition at the time of acquisition.
== 3. Features of the unification of law ==


More recently, however, there seems to be a change. In 1991, the Institute of International Law published a resolution according to which the acquisition of cultural objects is governed by the ''lex originis'', ie the law of that state from which the object originates. Also, export control is now decided according to that law (Arts&nbsp;2 and 3 of the Resolution, Yearbook of the Institute of International Law 64 II, 403&nbsp;ff). The UNIDROIT Convention of 24&nbsp;June 1995 followed the same policy in its chapter 2 (see 5. below), and also the new Belgian Statute of PIL of 16&nbsp;July 2004 accepted this idea and provides in Arts&nbsp;90 and 92 that cultural objects and stolen objects cannot be acquired if either the ''lex originis'' or—if more favourable for the protection of the object—the ''lex rei sitae'' prohibits the acquisition.
The term ‘unification of law’ is understood in this context as the unification of monetary law, not the unification of money. The unification of monetary law started at the end of World War II. The Agreement on the International Monetary Fund (IMF) was concluded during the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference, held from 1&nbsp;July to 22&nbsp;July 1944 in Bretton Woods. The IMF Agreement (or Bretton Woods Agreement) entered into force on 27&nbsp;December 1945 and established a new international monetary organization and partly unified the foreign exchange law of the contracting states. The International Monetary Fund founded a new international monetary system. The Special Drawing Rights (SDR), whose legal nature is uncertain, were created for that purpose. The SDR are sometimes qualified as international money and sometimes considered to be mere units of account. Article&nbsp;VIII(2)(b)(1) of the IMF Agreement is of particular importance for the unification of law. Under this provision, courts and administrative authorities of the IMF shall declare unenforceable any exchange contracts that involve the currency of any member state and which are contrary to the exchange control regulations of that member state. This provision was originally aimed at overcoming the unilateral aspect of international foreign exchange law. The Geneva Convention providing a Uniform Law of Bills of Exchange and Promissory Notes of 7&nbsp;June 1930 and the Geneva Convention providing a Uniform Law for Cheques of 19&nbsp;March 1930, both still in force, are also noteworthy. In relation to monetary obligations, two international agreements have been signed: the European Convention on Foreign Money Liabilities of 11&nbsp;December 1967, signed in Paris, and the European Convention on the Place of Payment of Money Liabilities of 16&nbsp;May 1972, signed in Basel. However, neither has entered into force. Since the 1990s, the efforts towards unification of law have focused on credit transfer. The increase of cross-border fund transfer has prompted [[UNCITRAL]] to work on a Model Law on International Credit Transfer. The 1992 Model Law’s purpose is to achieve a common definition of credit transfer and to dismantle the hurdles relating to international fund transfers. Directive&nbsp;2007/64 on payment services in the internal market is also based on the Model Law.  


== 4. Importance in European law ==
Regarding soft law, the [[UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (PICC)]] are of particular relevance. Articles&nbsp;6.1.9 and 6.1.10 rule on the currency of payment, the latter in case the parties fail to designate a currency of payment, and Art&nbsp;7.4.12 determines the currency in which to assess damages, as does Art&nbsp;7:108 PECL. In regard to the increasing importance of bank money and, consequently, the increasing role of the banks in international fund transfers, the recommendations of the Committee on Payment and Settlement System of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) should be mentioned. This Committee contributes to the unification of norms, principles and practice of payment systems, contributions which are necessary to strengthen the widespread international financial architecture.


The European Union does not have an independent policy with respect to the protection of cultural objects. In Art&nbsp;36 TFEU/30 EC ‘national treasures of artistic, historical or archaeological value’ are exempt from the free movement of goods between the Member States. Protection is awarded by the Member States, and the Union only obliges the Member States to enforce foreign rules prohibiting any removal of such goods. According to Dir&nbsp;93/7 on the Return of Cultural Objects Unlawfully Removed from the Territory of a Member State, all Member States and also Member States of the EEA (Iceland, Liechtenstein and Norway) must provide in their national implementing provisions that any cultural object needing a government licence for removal out of the country of origin must be returned if such a licence was not given and the object was removed across state borders. Any ''bona fide'' purchaser in the Member State that has to return the object must be compensated.
== 4. Europeanization of currency and currency&nbsp;law  ==


Regulation&nbsp;116/2009 on the Export of Cultural Objects deals with the question of which Member State is competent to give an export licence if a cultural object has to be exported to a third state. This Regulation aims at avoiding the risk that cultural objects of a Member State with severe export prohibitions are removed to a Member State with less stringent ones that would consequently allow the export.
The ‘certificate of birth’ of the common European currency is enshrined in the Maastricht Treaty (Arts&nbsp;127–144 TFEU/105–124 EC). However, the origin of the euro is far more remote. As early as 1970, the report of the Werner Group had already proposed a three-step process for the construction of a fully developed economic and monetary union. The process took longer than expected but a common currency of the [[European Union]] has become reality. After the establishment of the European Monetary System (EMS) and the determination of the convergence criteria setting the conditions for the entry of the Member States into the Eurozone, the third step of the process began on 1&nbsp;January 1999. The Eurozone has grown from the original 11 states to 17 states. The introduction of the euro was achieved by the use of Regulations. The first piece of legislation concerns the first monetary element, ie the unit of account. The unit of account is regulated by Reg&nbsp;1103/97 on certain provisions relating to the introduction of the euro, which provided for different measures: the conversion of 1&nbsp;ECU (which was a basket money) to €1; the principle of the continuity of legal instruments and the rounding rules after the conversion into euros. The ECU, which was solely a unit of account without monetary character, has hence been replaced by the euro. The gaps in this first regulation were then filled by Reg&nbsp;974/98 on the introduction of the euro. From 1&nbsp;January 1999, the euro has become the common currency of the Member States participating in the Eurozone and has replaced their national currencies at a predetermined conversion rate. In addition, Reg 975/98 dealt with the issue of denomination and technical specifications of euro coins intended for circulation. The conversion rates between the euro and the currencies of the participating Member States were determined on the eve of the introduction of the euro on 1&nbsp;January 1999 through Reg&nbsp;2866/98. Token money was introduced into circulation on 1&nbsp;January 2002. Concerning the monetary signs, Reg&nbsp;1338/2001 laying down measures necessary for the protection of the euro against counterfeiting was adopted. Since the euro exists as monetary unit and token money, the European legislature has concentrated its efforts on encouraging the circulation of bank money. This purpose has been achieved through the already mentioned Dir 2007/64 on payment services in the internal market; Dir 2009/44 on settlement finality in payment and securities settlement systems; Reg 924/2009 on cross-border payments in Euro; and Dir 2009/110 on the taking up, pursuit and prudential supervision of the business of electronic money institutions.
 
== 5. Importance in public international law ==
 
a)&nbsp;In the law of armed conflict, it was customary until about 1800 that the victorious party could plunder the defeated party and take booty at their discretion. Cultural objects were also taken as booty (eg the Egyptian obelisks in Rome, the Horses of St Mark of Venice from Constantinople, the Burgundy booty in Berne and the Bible of Ulfila from Prague in Uppsala) if they were not simply destroyed or damaged. This archaic attitude changed during the 19th&nbsp;century. The old rules of customary international law were replaced by the Hague Convention of 1907 concerning Laws and Customs of War on Land and the Hague Convention of 1954 on the Protection of Cultural Property in the Event of Armed Conflict, with its protocols. The Hague Convention of 1907 forbade the destruction or seizure of the enemy’s private property (Art&nbsp;23(1)(g)), made it illegal to attack or bombard undefended buildings (Art&nbsp;25), provided that steps must be taken to spare buildings dedicated to religion and historic monuments (Art&nbsp;27), prohibited the pillage of a town or place and pillage in general (Arts&nbsp;28 and 47) and prohibited the taking of private property and the confiscation of public property that is not being used for military operations (Art&nbsp;53). There is no special rule for cultural objects as such in the Hague Convention of 1907. Nonetheless, these objects are covered by the Convention and therefore the Federal Republic of Germany demanded from the Russian Federation the return of looted art which was taken out of Germany after World War II. At this time, looting and plundering was already forbidden by customary international law which did not make any exception with respect to restitution in kind. Also, bilateral treaties concluded after 1990 provide that art objects displaced after World War II should be returned to Germany. This is especially relevant for Russia according to the Treaty of 1992.
 
The existing regime lasted until 1954 when the Hague Convention of 14&nbsp;May 1954 on the Protection of Cultural Property in the Event of Armed Conflict dealt especially with cultural property, which is defined in Art&nbsp;1. The Hague Convention of 1954 seeks to safeguard cultural property against the foreseeable effects of an armed conflict by fixing a distinctive emblem to the objects and providing shelters for them. The First Protocol to the Convention obligates parties to not transport cultural objects abroad and, if they had been taken abroad for safekeeping, to return them. The Second Protocol of 26&nbsp;March 1999 regulates the enhanced protection for cultural property of great importance for humanity, establishes criminal responsibility for crimes against cultural property and improves institutional cooperation. Despite these efforts, the Library of Sarajevo was destroyed in 1992, in Baghdad the National Museum was plundered in 2003 and Iraqi archaeological sites are until now the principal domain of grave robbers. Here, it is not foreign enemies at work, but members of the state of origin. In such cases, other instruments become necessary.  
 
b)&nbsp;The first important Convention for the protection of cultural property in time of peace was the UNESCO Convention of 14&nbsp;November 1970 on the Means of Prohibiting and Preventing the Illicit Import, Export and Transfer of Ownership of Cultural Property. Based on policies from the era of decolonization, the Convention obliges every state to ban the import and acquisition of stolen or illegally exported cultural property, defined in Art&nbsp;1, and, if stolen or illegally exported, to return the objects to the state of origin (Art&nbsp;7). There are very few countries that took the Convention seriously and implemented it in national statutes. As an exception, the United States did implement it as did Switzerland, Germany and the Netherlands. Austria is about to do the same. Although not directly applicable, the UNESCO Convention of 1970 changed art trade considerably. Art&nbsp;trade violating the spirit of the Convention has been determined to be ‘improper’ and ‘not deserving to be protected under civil law’ (BGH 22&nbsp;June 1972, BGHZ 59, 82, 88). Nonetheless, the UNESCO Convention did not achieve the intended result of effectively protecting cultural property. Therefore, the Rome International Institute for the Unification of Private Law was asked by UNESCO to draft a Convention that directly prohibits the acquisition of stolen and illegally exported cultural objects. The outcome of this work is the UNIDROIT Convention of 24&nbsp;June 1995 on Stolen or Illegally Exported Cultural Objects, which today (1&nbsp;January 2011) is in force in 30 countries. These countries are not market states, but rather states of origin. The UNIDROIT Convention prohibits the acquisition of cultural objects that have been stolen from within a contracting state or illegally exported from a contracting state and requires that these objects be returned irrespective of a ''bona fide'' purchase. If there has been a ''bona fide'' purchase, the buyer has to be reasonably compensated by the state asking for return.  
 
c)&nbsp;Cultural property under water creates special problems because it is doubtful which state is responsible for the protection of such treasures. Cultural objects are not only found in territorial waters but also in the exclusive economic zone, on the continental shelf and in the high seas beyond any territorial waters. Therefore, it has to be decided which state is responsible for cultural objects and how to initiate international cooperation. These questions are now regulated by the UNESCO Convention of 2&nbsp;November 2001 on Underwater Cultural Heritage, which defines such ‘underwater cultural heritage’ in Art&nbsp;1(1).
 
d)&nbsp;Based on the UNESCO Convention of 16&nbsp;November 1972 Concerning the Protection of the World Cultural and Natural Heritage, certain monuments, places and natural sites located in member states are listed as being part of the world’s cultural and natural heritage and are to be preserved as such. In this regard, the Tower of London, Castel del Monte (Italy), the Statute of Liberty (United States, New York), the Pope’s Palace in Avignon (France) and Stonehenge (England) have been listed. The member states have to protect the objects, to support them and to make sure that they are preserved for future generations. In addition to that, the contracting states assume the obligation to heed these objects in their policies on building, housing, traffic, finance and research. Hence the World Heritage Convention exerts a considerable influence although it is not directly enforceable. This could be shown by the dispute concerning the site of the Dresden Valley, removed from the list of the World Cultural Heritage in 2009 as a result of the decision to build a four-lane bridge over it.
 
e)&nbsp;In recent years, intangible cultural heritage has received more attention. Therefore the UNESCO Convention of 17&nbsp;October 2003 for the Safeguarding of the Intangible Cultural Heritage was signed and two years later the UNESCO Convention of 20&nbsp;October 2005 on the Protection and Promotion of the Diversity of Cultural Expressions was added. Since then, certain performing arts and social practices of ethnic groups are also protected as well as the instruments with which these activities are exercised. Here, it is no longer movables that are protected but ethnic abilities.
 
f)&nbsp;The Council of Europe ([[Council of Europe (Harmonization of Private Law)|Council of Europe (harmonization of private law)]] [[Council of Europe (Institutional Aspects)|Council of Europe (institutional aspects)]]) has prepared several conventions, inter alia, on the protection of the archaeological heritage (1969, revised 1992), on the protection of the architectural heritage of Europe (1985), on offences relating to cultural property (1985) and on the value of cultural heritage for society (2005). These Conventions are not directly enforceable. Nonetheless, they exert a certain influence to the extent they serve as guidelines for offices of cultural affairs in the member states of the Council of Europe which, in turn, try to follow the policies of the conventions and achieve their goals.
 
g)&nbsp;Apart from formally drafted conventions or regulations by governments, as well as international or supranational organizations, there are many codes of conduct by professional organizations or institutions, eg the Code of Professional Ethics of the International Council of Museums in Paris. These sources are sometimes called soft law because, without being binding on the members of the profession, they exert a certain influence and give guidance to their behaviour. In the field of cultural property, the most important code is the Washington Conference Principles of 3&nbsp;December 1998 on Nazi-Confiscated Art&nbsp;Objects, confirmed on 5&nbsp;October 2000 in Vilnius/Lithuania and on 30&nbsp;June 2009 in Terezin/Czech Republic. These Principles try to persuade the state to conduct provenance research and, if possible, to return art objects that were taken from Jewish citizens. Based on the Principles, the German Federal Government, the German states and the regional German communities prepared a Statement of December 1999 stating that Germany will try to find objects that have not already been returned and will make restitution. A Guideline of February 2001 (revised in November 2007) confirms this attitude.
 
== 6. Future of protection of cultural property ==
 
There are many national, supranational and international instruments for the protection of cultural property. Also, voluntary and informal cooperation of state authorities has grown and improved. Trade with art objects has developed its own rules and, nonetheless, is in some countries handled more liberally than before. Loans from abroad are protected against seizure and subject to return proceedings in the state giving this return guarantee. Nevertheless, the future of the protection of cultural property is not so promising. Wars and local conflicts threaten cultural monuments, museums and libraries. The financial crisis of states has the effect that state protection is diminishing and private persons have to care for these objects. Natural catastrophes and environmental problems cause considerable damage and the growing tourism trade endangers the cultural heritage of mankind. Finally, the enforcement of protection is not ideal. Lack of money and growing mobility as well as communication (trade in cultural objects via the internet) make any supervision and enforcement extremely difficult.


==Literature==
==Literature==
Patrick O’Keefe and Lyndel V Prott, ''Law and the Cultural Heritage'','' vol&nbsp;1'' (1984) and ''vol&nbsp;3'' (1989); Kurt Siehr, ‘International Art&nbsp;Trade and the Law’ (1993) 243 Recueil des Cours 9; Guido Carducci, ''La restitution internationale des biens culturels et des objects d’art'' (1997); John Henry Merryman, ''Thinking About the Elgin Marbles. Critical Essays on Cultural Property'','' Art&nbsp;and Law'' (2000); Wojciech Kowalski, ‘Restitution of Works of Art&nbsp;Pursuant to Private and Public International Law’ (2001) 288 Recueil des Cours 9; Mariano J Aznar Gómez, ''La protección internacional del patrimonio cultural subacuátic'' (2004); Ralph E Lerner and Judith Bresler, ''Art&nbsp;Law'','' The Guide for Collectors'','' Investors'','' Dealers'','' and Artists'' (3rd&nbsp;edn, 2005); Kerstin Odendahl, ''Kulturgüterschutz. Entwicklung'','' Struktur und Dogmatik eines ebenenübergreifenden Normensystems'' (2005); Leonard DuBoff, Michael D Murray and Christy O King, ''The Deskbook of Art&nbsp;Law'' (2nd&nbsp;edn, 2006 (looseleaf)); Sarah Dromgoole (ed), ''The Protection of the Underwater Cultural Heritage'' (2nd&nbsp;edn, 2006); Jeanette Greenfield, ''The Return of Cultural Property'' (3rd&nbsp;edn, 2007); Haimo Schack, ''Kunst und Recht'' (2nd&nbsp;edn, 2009); Rudolf Stich, Wolfgang E Burhenne, Ernst-Rainer Hönes and Ursula Kunz (eds),'' Denkmalrecht der Länder und des Bundes'' (2009 (looseleaf)); Michael Anton, ''Rechtshandbuch Kulturgüterschutz und Kunstrestitutionsrecht'', ''6 vols ''(2010).</div>
Philippe Kahn (ed), ''Droit et monnaie'':'' Etats et espace monétaire transnational'' (1988); Hugo J Hahn, ''Währungsrecht'' (1990); Rémy Libchaber, ''Recherches sur la monnaie en droit privé'' (1992); Frederick A Mann, ''The Legal Aspect of Money'' (5th&nbsp;edn, 1992; new edn, 2005 by Charles Proctor); Andreas Blaschczok and Karsten Schmidt, ‘§§&nbsp;244–248 (Geldrecht)’ in ''von Staudingers Kommentar zum Bürgerlichen Gesetzbuch ''(13th&nbsp;edn, 1997); Helmut Grothe, ''Fremdwährungsverbindlichkeiten'' (1999); Mario Giovanoli (ed), ''International Monetary Law'':'' Issues for the New Millenium'' (2000); John Anthony Usher, ''The Law of Money and Financial Services in the European Community ''(2000); Caroline Kleiner, “Money in Private International Law: what are the problems, what are the solutions?” (2009) 11 Yearbook of Private International Law 565; Vaughan Black, ''Foreign Currency Claims in the Conflict of Laws'' (2010); Caroline Kleiner,'' La monnaie dans les relations privées internationales'' (2010).</div>




[[Category:A–Z]]
[[Category:A–Z]]
[[de:Kulturgüter]]
[[de:Währung]]

Latest revision as of 18:39, 5 June 2025

by Caroline Kleiner

1. Concept, objective and goal

Although currency is used in many different areas of law, no legal definition of this concept exists. Currency is a specific legal object that should not be confused with bank notes. Legal scholars often mention the relativity of this concept. It is indeed an abstract concept.

Currency, as a legal concept, should be distinguished from the notion of money. From an economic point of view, money is a medium of exchange, a unit of account and a measure of value. Conversely, currency is a legal concept: a specific monetary unit of a monetary system within a state or monetary zone. Currency is the backbone of a monetary system, which is itself the foundation of an economic order. Although both words exist in German (Geld and Währung) as well as in French (argent and monnaie), the distinction in English law is not exactly the same as the difference between Währung and Geld in German (for instance, the statute introducing the new Deutsche Mark in 1948 bore the title Währungsgesetz and not Geldgesetz). The concept of ‘money’ (Geld) is therefore broader than the concept of ‘currency’ (Währung), which refers to the specific money of a state, and yet is the basis of its definition.

A precise definition of the legal concept of currency is nonetheless hard to find. Currency is a wide-ranging concept that relates to many different legal areas, hence the elaboration of a general definition is challenging. The easiest approach consists in analysing the roles assumed by the concept of currency. In the context of legal relationships, currency has both an abstract and an actual function. The currency of account (Rechnungswährung, monnaie de compte) determines the value of the monetary obligation. It fulfils the abstract function of money. The currency of account also corresponds to the ‘institutional notion of money’. The currency of payment (die Zahlungswährung, monnaie de paiement) performs and discharges monetary obligations. It represents the actual function of money. Both functions, assuming respectively the role of a unit of account and a means of exchange, are intrinsically linked, yet they should be clearly distinguished from each other.

For a currency to fulfil both functions, it should contain different elements. The concept of currency can be restricted to three monetary components. All are necessary for the existence of a currency. First, the monetary unit, expressing a unit of value, plays the main role. A monetary unit is a unit of measure whose value is based on a convention. In the past, the value of a monetary unit used to be determined by a specific weight of noble metal. Today, its value is determined in accordance with the market demand. The second essential element composing a currency is located in its abstract purchasing power. Friedrich Carl von Savigny identified the notion of abstract purchasing power. It means that the currency implies a specific and subjective right that performs all types of obligations, even future ones. Thirdly, the unit of account reflecting a purchasing power needs an embodiment or a ‘bearer’ in order to materialize. These two last components are the core elements which enable a currency to serve as a medium of exchange. Moreover, the purchasing power can be embodied in different ‘bearers’. These embodiments or ‘bearers’ are the external aspect of the currency.

It is common to distinguish (at least in continental Europe) between coins, banknotes, bank money (also called credit money, Buchgeld) and electronic money. But from a legal point of view, these bearers of purchasing power should be differentiated into only two categories. Coins and notes are monetary signs. Monetary signs are ‘commodities, which are divided into units of account, which serve as a medium of exchange to their nominal value according to the law, and which as such are recognized by the laws and cannot be refused by any creditor’ (Karsten Schmidt). Since the abrogation of the duty of the Central Bank to exchange notes against gold, bank notes can no longer be compared with bills of exchange. Coins and bank notes are therefore governed by the same legal regime as the one applied to commodities, but with some exceptions, such as their capacity to serve as a legal means of payment and the provisions against counterfeiting. Conversely, bank or credit money, as well as electronic money, are not commodities, but are credits towards private institutions. They are mostly bank deposits. The appellation bank money or credit money comes from the fact that the circulation of money is operated only under book transfers, without any manual exchange of any monetary commodities. In that perspective, no distinction should be made between bank money and e-money. The only difference is that nowadays all transfers are made electronically. Regardless of this fact, coins and banknotes (token money) and bank money merely represent different external forms of purchasing power which are divided into units of account and form, all together, money. These three monetary elements are closely linked with one another, but they are still regulated by different norms. This tripartite composition of a currency explains why, irrespective of its function in monetary obligations, different types of legal norms find application.

In private law and in private international law (PIL), money raises a large number of questions. The answers to such questions depend on the functions money fulfils. In the context of monetary obligations, the first question to be answered is the determination of the money of account. According to the majority of scholars, the determination of which money is due is governed by the law of the obligation. This is the Swiss (Art 147 § 2 of the Swiss Private International Law Act (SPILA)) as well as the German view. In French law, the case law shows an inclination to analyse the question as an issue relating to the interpretation of contract. Secondly, one should consider the question of the value of the unit of account. Where the parties have foreseen a monetary clause, this clause is governed by the law applicable to the contract in which it is enshrined (lex contractus). German law and English law follow this approach. French case law has drawn another method and invented a new substantive rule, upon which monetary clauses in international contracts are always valid (Cour de Cassation, Cass. civ. 1re, 21 June 1950, Messageries maritimes, Rev. crit 1950, 609). If the parties have not foreseen such a clause, then the question arises as to which legal order decides upon the value of the currency of account, that is to say, whether the nominalism principle should apply. The application of the so-called lex monetae (Währungsstatut) was widespread up until the end of World War II. Today, the prominent position is to apply the law of the contract. One of the questions raised in relation to the currency of payment is precisely the determination of the currency of payment. More particularly, the question is whether an obligation providing for a foreign currency of payment can be discharged in local money. If German law is applicable, § 244 Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch (BGB) provides that if a money debt stated in a currency other than the euro is payable within the country, then payment may be made in euros unless payment in the other currency has been expressly agreed to. In the context of conflict of laws, in Swiss law the determination of the currency of payment is governed by the law of payment, that is to say, the law of the place of payment or the lex loci solutionis (Art 147 § 3 SPILA). This is also the solution enshrined in Art 10(2) of the Rome Convention and Art 12(2) of Rome I Regulation (Reg 593/2008), insofar as the currency of payment is seen as a manner of performance. This solution is linked to the fact that the overriding mandatory provisions (lois de police) of the state where the payment takes place are often applied.

2. Evolving tendencies of the law

The theories aimed at explaining the origin of money were uncontested for a long time. According to the state theory of money developed by the economist Georg Friedrich Knapp, ‘[m]oney is a creature of law’. This theory constrains the concept because according to it, only monetary commodities issued by a state could be seen as money, thus excluding bank money. However, what can be concluded from this theory is that the state monopoly over money and its monopoly over the issuance of coins and notes are a component part of state sovereignty. It is beyond doubt that the state—or a supranational organization whose sovereignty has been granted by states—alone has the privilege to confer to commodities the status of legal tender and to authorize their circulation. As a consequence, only the state which issued a currency can define and regulate it. This principle was first set forth in 1929 by the Permanent Court of International Justice (PCIJ 12 July 1929, Serbian Loans and Brazilian Loans).

In contrast to the state theory of money, Arthur Nussbaum developed the sociological theory of money. According to Nussbaum, money is whatever is considered as such in the economic community or in the market. His theory explains particularly the phenomenon of emergency currency. The power of the state to create and circulate money is a privilege of the state, but is not a requirement for a currency to exist. However, the controversy on whether money is a creature of the law or a result of social activities is no longer relevant. As a legal institution, currency is based on its recognition by the state and is, in this sense, the product of legal orders. But it is absolutely not contradictory that money is the product of economic activities and in the meantime a product of the rule of law.

The debate has now shifted from the origin of money to its future. Two tendencies in the evolution of the private law of currency can be assessed. The first one concerns the ‘bearer’ or the manifestation of money (how the purchasing power is incorporated): it is related to the dematerialization of the circulation of money. The second tendency focuses on the monetary unit.

The abstract nature of money was brought to light because of the dematerialization of its external forms. In the past, many authors argued that only token money (coins and notes), which were dealt with as chattels, corresponded to the notion of money. An amount of units registered on a bank account was a credit and not money. But with the exponential increase of cashless payments, the definition of money has obviously changed. Bank deposits are henceforth seen as money because they assume the function of money. E-money merely represents a step forward to the dematerialization of money. Only the manner of book entries has evolved; the so-called e-money remains money, since it is still evaluated through accounting units and embodies an abstract purchasing power.

In the meantime, the unification of currencies, for which the euro currency is the most representative example, is worth noticing. But this is not the unique example. In Africa, the Franc CFA is still shared by some former French colonies. A regional monetary union can also be achieved by means other than international conventions. The so-called dollarization that has emerged in Latin America, as well as the unilateral introduction of the euro in some European countries not part of the euro zone (Monaco, Andorra), illustrate this tendency. The states of the Mercosur are currently dealing with the issue of whether they should introduce a common currency or not. This tendency raises different questions: how the competence relating to money should be exercised and how to react to the unilateral adoption of the money by third states. As far as the euro is concerned, the Member States of the European Monetary Union have transferred their sovereign power. The German Federal Constitutional Court asserted that the transfer of competence was compatible with the German Constitution (Grundgesetz) in the Maastricht Judgment of 12 October 1993 (BVerfGE 89, 155). The European Central Bank (ECB) only has competence over monetary policy and the competence to decide on monetary issues. The European legislature also provided for the principle of continuity of legal instruments in order to ensure the recognition of the euro by third states (Art 3 Reg 1103/97).

3. Features of the unification of law

The term ‘unification of law’ is understood in this context as the unification of monetary law, not the unification of money. The unification of monetary law started at the end of World War II. The Agreement on the International Monetary Fund (IMF) was concluded during the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference, held from 1 July to 22 July 1944 in Bretton Woods. The IMF Agreement (or Bretton Woods Agreement) entered into force on 27 December 1945 and established a new international monetary organization and partly unified the foreign exchange law of the contracting states. The International Monetary Fund founded a new international monetary system. The Special Drawing Rights (SDR), whose legal nature is uncertain, were created for that purpose. The SDR are sometimes qualified as international money and sometimes considered to be mere units of account. Article VIII(2)(b)(1) of the IMF Agreement is of particular importance for the unification of law. Under this provision, courts and administrative authorities of the IMF shall declare unenforceable any exchange contracts that involve the currency of any member state and which are contrary to the exchange control regulations of that member state. This provision was originally aimed at overcoming the unilateral aspect of international foreign exchange law. The Geneva Convention providing a Uniform Law of Bills of Exchange and Promissory Notes of 7 June 1930 and the Geneva Convention providing a Uniform Law for Cheques of 19 March 1930, both still in force, are also noteworthy. In relation to monetary obligations, two international agreements have been signed: the European Convention on Foreign Money Liabilities of 11 December 1967, signed in Paris, and the European Convention on the Place of Payment of Money Liabilities of 16 May 1972, signed in Basel. However, neither has entered into force. Since the 1990s, the efforts towards unification of law have focused on credit transfer. The increase of cross-border fund transfer has prompted UNCITRAL to work on a Model Law on International Credit Transfer. The 1992 Model Law’s purpose is to achieve a common definition of credit transfer and to dismantle the hurdles relating to international fund transfers. Directive 2007/64 on payment services in the internal market is also based on the Model Law.

Regarding soft law, the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (PICC) are of particular relevance. Articles 6.1.9 and 6.1.10 rule on the currency of payment, the latter in case the parties fail to designate a currency of payment, and Art 7.4.12 determines the currency in which to assess damages, as does Art 7:108 PECL. In regard to the increasing importance of bank money and, consequently, the increasing role of the banks in international fund transfers, the recommendations of the Committee on Payment and Settlement System of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) should be mentioned. This Committee contributes to the unification of norms, principles and practice of payment systems, contributions which are necessary to strengthen the widespread international financial architecture.

4. Europeanization of currency and currency law

The ‘certificate of birth’ of the common European currency is enshrined in the Maastricht Treaty (Arts 127–144 TFEU/105–124 EC). However, the origin of the euro is far more remote. As early as 1970, the report of the Werner Group had already proposed a three-step process for the construction of a fully developed economic and monetary union. The process took longer than expected but a common currency of the European Union has become reality. After the establishment of the European Monetary System (EMS) and the determination of the convergence criteria setting the conditions for the entry of the Member States into the Eurozone, the third step of the process began on 1 January 1999. The Eurozone has grown from the original 11 states to 17 states. The introduction of the euro was achieved by the use of Regulations. The first piece of legislation concerns the first monetary element, ie the unit of account. The unit of account is regulated by Reg 1103/97 on certain provisions relating to the introduction of the euro, which provided for different measures: the conversion of 1 ECU (which was a basket money) to €1; the principle of the continuity of legal instruments and the rounding rules after the conversion into euros. The ECU, which was solely a unit of account without monetary character, has hence been replaced by the euro. The gaps in this first regulation were then filled by Reg 974/98 on the introduction of the euro. From 1 January 1999, the euro has become the common currency of the Member States participating in the Eurozone and has replaced their national currencies at a predetermined conversion rate. In addition, Reg 975/98 dealt with the issue of denomination and technical specifications of euro coins intended for circulation. The conversion rates between the euro and the currencies of the participating Member States were determined on the eve of the introduction of the euro on 1 January 1999 through Reg 2866/98. Token money was introduced into circulation on 1 January 2002. Concerning the monetary signs, Reg 1338/2001 laying down measures necessary for the protection of the euro against counterfeiting was adopted. Since the euro exists as monetary unit and token money, the European legislature has concentrated its efforts on encouraging the circulation of bank money. This purpose has been achieved through the already mentioned Dir 2007/64 on payment services in the internal market; Dir 2009/44 on settlement finality in payment and securities settlement systems; Reg 924/2009 on cross-border payments in Euro; and Dir 2009/110 on the taking up, pursuit and prudential supervision of the business of electronic money institutions.

Literature

Philippe Kahn (ed), Droit et monnaie: Etats et espace monétaire transnational (1988); Hugo J Hahn, Währungsrecht (1990); Rémy Libchaber, Recherches sur la monnaie en droit privé (1992); Frederick A Mann, The Legal Aspect of Money (5th edn, 1992; new edn, 2005 by Charles Proctor); Andreas Blaschczok and Karsten Schmidt, ‘§§ 244–248 (Geldrecht)’ in von Staudingers Kommentar zum Bürgerlichen Gesetzbuch (13th edn, 1997); Helmut Grothe, Fremdwährungsverbindlichkeiten (1999); Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millenium (2000); John Anthony Usher, The Law of Money and Financial Services in the European Community (2000); Caroline Kleiner, “Money in Private International Law: what are the problems, what are the solutions?” (2009) 11 Yearbook of Private International Law 565; Vaughan Black, Foreign Currency Claims in the Conflict of Laws (2010); Caroline Kleiner, La monnaie dans les relations privées internationales (2010).